WAREHOUSE BANKING
Jason Roderick Donaldson Giorgia Piacentino Anjan Thakor
Washington University in St. Louis
August 31, 2015
Abstract
We develop a new theory of banking that provides a view of liquidity creation that
differs significantly from the existing paradigm. The theory links modern-day banks to
their historical origin as warehouses. When the warehouse accepts deposits, it issues
“warehouse receipts,” claims on deposits it safeguards, as “proof of deposits, but this
suffices neither to create liquidity nor to make the warehouse a bank. Our main result is
that the warehouse becomes a bank and creates ex ante aggregate liquidity only when it
makes loans in “fake” receipts—i.e. receipts that are observationally identical to authen-
tic receipts, but are not backed by dep osits. In other words, what creates liquidity and
economic growth is not banks’ deposit-taking per se—banks issuing receipts in exchange
for the deposit of goods—but rather the combination of this with account-keeping (i.e.
warehousing) and fake-receipt-based lending. On the policy front our theory suggests
that the currently-contemplated suggestions to have narrow banking or impose liq-
uidity requirements will inhibit aggregate liquidity creation, whereas increasing bank
capital will enhance bank liquidity creation. This stands in contrast with the policy
prescriptions of models of bank liquidity creation based on deposit-taking and lending
but without warehousing and fake-receipt issuance. We also show that a tighter central
bank monetary policy does not always reduce liquidity creation—we provide conditions
under which it leads to higher liquidity creation by banks.
For their helpful comments, we thank Franklin Allen, Ulf Axelson, Juliane Begena u, Liam Br unt, Mike
Burkart, Doug Dia mond, Co lm Friel, Anand Goel, Itay Goldstein, Charles Goodhart, Denis Gromb, Charles
Kahn, Peter Koudijs, Andrey Malenko, Nadya Malenko, Clemens Otto, George Pennacchi, Uday Rajan,
Adriano Rampini, Javier Suarez, Lucy White, Andrew Winton, Randy Wr ight and seminar par ticipa nts at
the Sixth Bank of Po rtugal Conference on Financial I ntermediation, the 2015 European Summer Symposium
in Financial Markets at Gerzensee, the 2015 IDC Summer Finance Conference, the 2015 Summer Money
Workshop at the St Louis Fed, and Washington University in St. Louis. We alone ar e responsible for any
remaining errors.
The banks in their lending business are not only not limited by their own
capital; they are not, at least immediately, limited by any capital whatever; by
concentrating in their hands almost all payments, they themselves create the
money required...
Wicks ell (1907)
1
Introduction
Banking is an old business. The invention of banking precedes the invention of coinage
by several thousand years.
1
Banks evolved from ancient warehouses, where cattle, grain,
and precious metals were depos ited for storage. For example, in ancient Egypt, grain
harvests were “deposited” (or stored) in centralized warehouses and depositors could
write orders for the withdrawal of certain quantities of grain as means of payment.
These orders constituted some of the earliest paper money. Eventually the warehouses
for the safe storage of commodities began making loans, thereby evolving into modern
banks (see Williams (1986) and Lawson (1855), for example). By extending credit, these
institutions transformed from simple warehouses of liquidity to creators of liquidity. To
this day, the same institutions that provide safekeeping services also engage in the
bulk of lending in the economy and are responsible for significant liquidity creation
(e.g., Berger and Bouwman (2009)). Modern commercial and retail banks keep deposit
accounts, provide payment services and act as custodians as well as make corporate
and consumer loans.
Why do modern banks offer deposit-taking, account-keeping, payment, and custodial—
namely, warehousing—services within the same institution that provides lending ser-
vices? How do banks that combine warehousing and lending services create liquidity?
What does a theory of banking that addresses these questions have to say about regu-
latory initiatives like bank capital and liquidity requirements and proposals like narrow
banking?
In this paper, we address these questions by developing a model of banking based
on the warehousing function of the bank. In our model, the institutions that provide
the warehousing services endogenously perform the lending in the economy. The model
relies on two key assumptions. First, warehouses have an efficient storage technology
and, second, no firm’s output is pledgeable,
2
so debt written on a firm’s future cash
flow is not readily enforceable. Warehouses use their superior storage technology to
1
Banking seems to have originated in ancient Mesopotamia and some of the earliest recorded laws per-
taining banks (banking reg ulation) were part of the Code of Hammurabi.
2
See Ho lmström and Tiro le (2 011) for a list of “...several reasons why this [non-pledgeability] is by and
large reality” (p. 3).
1
circumvent the non-pledgeability problem. The warehouse’s ability to do this stems
from the fact that it is costly for firms to store their output privately, so they want to
deposit their output in a warehouse that can store it at a lower cost.
3
However, once
a firm deposits with the warehouse, the deposit can then be seized by the warehouse.
Thus, when the costs to private storage are high enough, it becomes incentive compat-
ible for firms to repay their debts in order to access warehouses’ storage services. This
mechanism explains why the same institutions should provide both the warehousing
and lending services in the economy.
4
Our model of warehouse banking leads to a new perspective on banks’ liquidity
creation. In our model, as in ancient Egypt, the receipts that warehouses issue for
deposits circulate as a medium of exchange—they constitute private money. This is
the first step in the bank’s creation of funding liquidity, which we define as the bank-
linked elevation of the initial liquidity that is allocated to productive inves tments.
5
The
second step in the liquidity creation process—and the key reason that banks increase
aggregate funding liquidity—is that they make loans in warehouse receipts rather than
in deposited goods. When banks make loans, they issue new receipts—“fake receipts”—
that are not backed by any deposits. Despite the lack of deposit-backing, these receipts
provide firms with working capital, allowing them to make more productive investments.
Note that banks create ex ante liquidity only when they make loans in fake receipts. If
the warehouse only takes deposits and issues receipts for them, it creates no liquidity
because it is simply exchanging one liquid as set for another—exchanging a liquid receipt
for a liquid deposit of real goods or central bank money.
Our warehousing view of banking provides some new insights into financial regu-
latory policy. One proposal is narrow banking. We interpret a narrow bank as an
institution that can invest its deposits in only “safe” assets, namely in cash or mar-
ketable liquid securities such as sovereign bonds (see Pennacchi (2012)). The proposal
forces the separation of the warehousing and lending functions of banks. Our analysis
suggests that banks create liquidity only when they perform this dual function, imply-
ing that narrow banks create no liquidity. Less extreme proposals, such as the liquidity
(reserve) ratio in Basel III, demand that banks invest at least a specified fraction of
their assets in cash and marketable liquid securities. These too stifle banks’ liquidity
3
The assumption is somewhat similar to the a ssumption in Allen and Gale (1998) that the storage tech-
nology availa ble to ba nk s is strictly more productive than the storag e technology available to consumers. As
we discuss later, this cost advantage for the warehouse may also stem from being in a privileged position of
power, like the a ncie nt warehouses from which banks evolved; these were linked to places of worship and/o r
the k ing’s tre asury.
4
In support of this mechanism, Skrastins (2015) uses a differences-in-differe nce s research design to demon-
strate that agricultural lenders in Brazil extend more credit when they merge with grain silos, i.e. banks
lend more when they are also warehouses.
5
We use the term “funding liquidity” in the sense in which it is used by Brunnermeier and Pedersen
(2009).
2
creation in our set-up, since they prevent banks from issuing fake receipts to expand the
supply of liquidity. In an extension, we contrast the effect of liquidity requirements with
the eff ect of capital (equity) requirements, which can actually enhance banks’ ability
to create liquidity by reducing moral hazard problems between banks and depositors,
making warehousing relatively more efficient. We also extend the model to include a
central bank and argue that a tighter monetary policy does not alway s lead to lower
liquidity creation. We establish conditions under which such a policy can actually
encourage lending by warehouse-banks.
Our model stands in contrast to the contemporary literature on why banks exist.
The only assumption we make on banks is that they have a storage technology. They
have no superior ability to screen or to monitor loans in an environment of asymmetric
information, as in Diamond (1984) and Ramakrishnan and Thakor (1984). Because we
assume that all agents are risk neutral, banks also do not provide better risk sharing for
risk averse depositors as in Bryant (1980) and Diamond and Dybvig (1983). Technolog-
ical and financial developments have diminished informational frictions and provided
alternatives to banks for risk-sharing (see the discussion in Coval and Thakor (2005)).
This s hould have led to a decline in financial intermediaries’ share of output (and cor-
porate profits) in developed economies, but their financial sectors have continued to
grow. This suggests that other forces also determine the demand for banking services;
we suggest that warehousing-type financial services may be one important determinant,
one linked with the very origins of banking. In fact, the largest deposit bank in the
world today, Bank of New York–Mellon, is usually classified as a custodian bank, i.e.
an institution responsible for the safeguarding, or warehousing, of financial assets.
Our paper is also related to the literature on liquidity creation by banks which relies
on the role of intermediaries as providers of liquidity insurance. Important contribu-
tions include Allen and Gale (1998), Allen, Carletti, and Gale (2014), Bryant (1980),
Diamond and Dybvig (1983), and Postlewaite and Vives (1987). In our model, banks
create liquid securities, since they issue receipts that constitute private money, and they
also create aggregate liquidity since more capital is directed into productive investment
with the bank than without. In other words, banks enhance funding liquidity. This
contrasts with the model in Diamond and Dybvig (1983) and other models of that genre
in at least five important respects, discussed below.
First, in Diamond and Dybvig (1983), the bank creates liquid securities, namely
demand-deposit contracts, to raise funds to invest in illiquid projects. However, the
bank does not create aggregate funding liquidity, since no more is invested in the illiq-
uid projects than would be absent the bank. In our model, the bank creates aggregate
funding liquidity precisely because it can create liquid securities—warehouse receipts—
with which to make loans. Since the receipts circulate as a medium of exchange, they
3
provide working capital to firms, expanding the total supply of liquidity available for
investment. Second, in existing models of bank liquidity creation, aggregate investment
is typically bounded by the total initial endowment of liqui dity in the economy. Banks
are limited to taking deposits and lending them out. Not so in our model. Indeed, in
aggregate firms invest in more capital and labor than the initial aggregate endowment of
liquidity in the economy, something that is impossible with the non-bank direct invest-
ment outcome. That is, in our model, lending also creates deposits. Third, models like
Bryant (1980) and Diamond and Dybvig (1983) focus on the bank’s interactions with
depositors as the source of liquidity creation, with uncertainty about time preferences
creating a preference for liquidity by (risk-averse) dep ositors. In other words, liquidity
creation is viewed as being synonymous with consumption insurance—the bank pro-
vides risk averse depositors with higher interim consumption than possible with direct
investment in the project that the bank invests its deposits in. Thus, even though the
depositor has just as liquid an asset by keeping his money in his pocket as he does by
depositing it in a bank, he obtains higher interim consumption and hence better risk
sharing with a deposit.
6
In contrast, our model focuses on the asset side of the bank’s
balance s heet as a result of our different definition of liquidity creation. Fourth, in the
existing models of bank liquidity creation, coordination failures among depositors can
lead to bank runs, an issue that does not arise in our model. Finally, while in the
existing models bank capital either plays no role in liquidity creation or is viewed as
impeding bank liquidity creation, in our model we show that it enhances bank liquidity
creation.
This focus on the bank’s assets, along with our assumption that all agents are
risk neutral, means that bank liquidity creation is decoupled from risk preferences.
Risk sharing for depositors is thus neither necessary nor sufficient for ex ante liquidity
creation by the bank in our framework, although deposits are an important reason why
the bank exists in the first place. Liquidity creation is manifested through the lending
of fake receipts. In this sense, our approach in which bank lending creates deposits is
reminiscent of Hahn (1920):
7
We thus maintain—contrary to the entire literature on banking and credit—
that the primary business of banks is not the liability business, especially
the deposit business, but in general and in each and every case an asset
transaction of a bank must have previously taken place, in order to allow
the possibility of a liability business and to cause it. The liability business
of banks is nothing but a reflex of prior credit extension.... (H ahn, 1920, p.
29)
6
Jacklin (1987) shows that if the owner of the project that the bank invests in were to issue traded equity
that paid a dividend at the interim date, the same risk sharing can be achieved as provided by bank deposits.
7
See also Werner (2014) and the “g oldsmith anecdote” in Greenbaum, Thakor, and Boot (2015)
4
Keynes makes a related point:
It is not unnatural to think of deposits of a bank as being created by the
public through the deposits of cash representing either savings or amounts
which are not for the time being required to meet expenditures. But the
bulk of the deposits arise out of the action of the banks themselves, for by
granting loans, allowing money to be drawn on an overdraft or purchasing
securities, a bank creates a credit in its books which is the equivalent of a
deposit. (Keynes in his contribution to the Macmillan Committee, 1931, p.
34)
We view our paper as offering a view of bank liquidity creation that complements the
consumption insurance view in the existing literature, a view that has provided deep in-
sights into a variety of phenomena like bank runs and deposit insurance (Bryant (1980)
and Diamond and Dybvig (1983)), financial crises (e.g. Allen and Gale (1998)), and the
role of financial intermediaries vis-à-vis markets (e.g. Allen and Gale (2004)). Juxta-
posing our analysis with the existing literature, liquidity creation is seen to have two
important dimensions: consumption insurance for depositors/savers and elevated fund-
ing liquidity for entrepreneurs/borrowers. These mutually-reinforcing views of bank
liquidity creation are consistent with the idea that banks create liquidity by both tak-
ing in deposits and selling loan commitments (e.g. Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein (2002)).
In addition to providing a different perspective on the role of banks and what they
do to create liquidity, our paper also provides a microfoundation for the assumption
that cash flow diversion destroys value, which is common in the finance literate (e.g.
Bolton and Scharfstein (1990) and Hart and M oore (1998)). In these models, if a bor-
rower diverts his cash flow rather than repays his creditor, his cash flow typically de-
creases by an exogenous, borrower-specific constant. In our model, such a number arises
endogenously as the ratio of depreciation given private storage to the returns on the
warehouses’ technology. Note that this suggests that the costs of diversion should not
be borrower-specific in general, in the sense that they depend not only on the borrower’s
technology, but on the creditor’s technology as well.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides an example in a
simplified set-up in which all the key forces of the model are at work. Section 3 develops
the formal model. Section 4 contains the solution of the model. Section 5 s olves two
benchmark models: (i) one in which warehouses cannot issue fake receipts and (ii) the
first-best allocation. Section 6 contains the main results. It presents analysis of liquidity
creation and fractional reserves. Section 7 considers the welfare implications of four
policies: liquidity requirements, narrow banking, capital requirements, and monetary
policy. Finally, Section 8 concludes. The appendix contains all proofs and a glossary
of notation.
5
2 Motivating Example
In this subsection, we write a numerical example that illustrates the main mechanism at
work in a simplified setup. We write the example with just three players, one farmer,
one laborer, and one warehouse. We examine a sequence of increasingly rich cases
to demonstrate the efficiency gains from warehousing and from issuing fake receipts.
Specifically, we consider: (1) the case without a warehouse, (2) the case in which a
warehouse provides only safe-keeping services but does not lend, (3) the case in which a
warehouse provides both safe-keeping and lending services, and (4) the first-best case,
in which the allocation is efficient.
The analysis of the example shows that, even without lending, warehousing alone
increases efficiency by providing more efficient storage. This efficiency gain is merely
technological, however; introducing a better storage technology increases terminal out-
put. But when a warehouse can issue f ake receipts, it does more to improve efficiency.
By issuing fake receipts, the warehouse creates liq uidity th at the farmer invests produc-
tively. This efficiency gain is allocational and is much more important than the simple
technological efficiency gain. When the warehouse issues fake receipts, it allows other
players in the economy to invest in more efficient technologies. Finally, the analysis
of the first-best allocation suggests that there is an efficiency loss in the second bes t
even when the warehouse can is sue fake receipts, it still creates less liquidity than in
the first-best.
The setup of the example is as follows. There are three dates, Date 0, Date 1, and
Date 2. The farmer has an endowment e of twelve units of grain at Date 0 and no one
else has any grain. At Date 0 the farmer can borrow B from the warehouse at gross
rate one. We assume that warehouse dep os it rates and wages w are also all set equal
to one.
8
The farmer produces over the period from Date 0 to Date 1 and he stores his
output over the period from Date 1 to Date 2. I f the farmer stores his grain privately, it
depreciates at δ percent, and we choose to set δ = 20%; if he stores it in a warehouse, it
does not depreciate. This can be viewed as the warehouse havi ng better defense against
theft, for reasons we explain later. The farmer’s production technology transforms a
unit of labor and a unit of grain at Date 0 into f our units of grain at Date 1 with
constant returns. In other words, the farmer has a Leontief p roduction function in the
first perio d that takes grain investment i, which we will refer to as “capital investment,”
and labor and produces output y = 4 min {i, } at Date 1. We assume that this output
is not pledgeable; however, a warehouse can seize the deposits it holds. Suppose there
is no discounting, so workers are willing to store grain in warehouses at the deposit rate
8
These prices—i.e. rates and wages—result from competition in the full model, leaving rents to the farmer.
We ta ke them as given in this example for simplicity.
6
of one. Everyone consumes only at Date 2.
The parameter values are summarized in Figure 1 and the timing is illustrated in
Figure 2.
Figure 1: Summary of notation and values in example in Section 2 .
Quantity
Notation Value in Example
Farmer’s endowment e 12
Farmer’s technology
y 4 min {i, }
Depreciation rate δ 20%
Wage
w 1
Figure 2: A Simplified Timeline Representation of the Sequence of Moves
Date 0
the farmer has endowment e and borrows B from the warehouse
he invests i in grain, and w in labor
the lab orer exerts la bor and deposits his wages w in the warehouse
Date 1
the farmer produces y
he either repays and deposits or diverts and stores privately
Date 2
the farmer, laborer, and warehouse consume
Definition of liquidity creation: We refer to the farmer’s expenditure on capital
and labor i + w as the “total investment.” We measure liquidity creation by the ratio
Λ of the farmer’s total investment to his initial endowment,
Λ =
i + w
e
.
7
No warehousing. Consider first the case in which there is no warehousing. Thus,
the farmer must pay the laborer in grain. To maximize his Date 2 consumption, the
farmer maximizes his Date 1 output and then stores his output from Date 1 to Date
2. To maximize his Date 1 output, he invests in equal amounts of capital i and labor
(as a result of the Leontief technology). Since his endowment is twelve and wages are
one, he sets i = = 6 and produces y = 4 × 6 = 24 units of grain. He then stores his
grain privately from Date 1 to Date 2 and this grain depreciates by twenty percent; the
farmer’s final payoff is (1 20%) × 24 = 19.2 units. Λ
nw
= 1, so there is no liquidity
creation.
Warehousing but no fake receipts. Now consider the case where there is a
warehouse, but that it performs only the function of safekeeping. When a depositor
(the farmer or the laborer) deposits grain in the warehouse, the warehouse issues receipts
and holds the grain until it is withdrawn. In this case, the farmer again maximizes his
Date 1 output in order to maximize his Date 2 consumption. Again, he will invest
equal amounts of capital and labor. He cannot borrow from the warehouse, so he again
just divides his endowment fifty-fifty between capital investment and labor, setting
i = = 6 and producing y = 4 × 6 = 24 units of grain. He now s tores his grain in the
warehouse from Date 1 to Date 2. Since it is warehoused, the grain does not depreciate;
the farmer’s final payoff is 24 units. Warehousing has added 4.8 units to the farmer’s
consumption by increasing efficiency in storage. But the warehouse has not created any
liquidity for the farmer since the initial investment in the technology i + wℓ = e = 12 is
the same as in the case in which there is no warehouse. There is no liquidity creation,
Λ
nr
= 1.
Warehousing with fake receipts. Now consider the case in which there is a
warehouse that provides not only safe-keeping but also lends. Since the farmer’s tech-
nology is highly productive, he wishes to borrow to scale it up. But the farmer already
holds all twelve units of grain in the economy, so how can he scale up his production
even further? The key is that the f armer can borrow from the warehouse in warehouse
receipts. Observe that the receipts the warehouse uses to make loans are n ot backed
by grain; they are “fake receipts.” However, if the laborer accepts payment from the
farmer in these fake receipts, they are still valuable to the farmer—they provide him
with “working capital” to pay the laborer.
The farmer again s ets his capital investment equal to his labor investment, i = .
Given that he can borrow B in receipts from the warehouse, however, he can now
invest a total up to i + w = e + B. Thus, recalling that wages w are one, his optimal
investment is
i =
e + B
2
= 6 +
B
2
(1)
8
and the corresponding Date 1 output is
y = 4i = 24 + 2B. (2)
Given that this technology is highly productive and has constant returns to scale, the
farmer wishes to expand production as much as possible. The amount he can borrow
from the warehouse, however, is limited by the amount that he can credibly promise to
repay. Since we have assumed that the farmer’s output is not pledgeable, his creditor
(i.e., the warehouse) cannot enforce the repayment of his debt. However, if the farmer
deposits in the warehouse, it is possible for the warehouse to seize the deposit. Thus,
after the farmer produces, he faces a tradeoff between not depositing and depositing.
If he does not deposit, he stores privately, so his grain depreciates, but he avoids
repayment. If he does dep osit, he avoids depreciation, but the warehouse can seize his
deposit and force repayment. The warehouse lends to the farmer only if repayment is
incentive compatible. For the repayment to be incentive compatible, the farmer must
prefer to deposit in the warehouse and repay his debt rather than to store the grain
privately and default on his debt. This is the case if the following inequality holds
y B (1 20%)y. (3)
The maximum the farmer can borrow B is thus given by
24 + 2B
B =
1 20%

24 + 2B
, (4)
or B = 8. This corresponds to i = = 10. The liquidity creation is given by
Λ =
i + w
e
=
10 + 10
12
=
5
3
. (5)
The farmer is able to scale up his production only when the warehouse makes
loans by writing fake receipts. In other words, liquidity is created on the asset side,
not the deposit side, of the warehouse’s balance sheet. When a warehouse makes a
loan, it creates both an illiquid asset, the loan, and a liquid liability, the fake receipt.
This is liquidity transformation, one of the fundamental economic roles of banks. Our
model suggests, however, that liquidity transformation occurs entirely when banks make
loans—it is not necessary that banks fund themselves with liquid deposits and then,
separately, make illiquid loans.
If the farmer could pay the labor on credit, he would not need to borrow from the
warehouse and he could expand production even further. However, an impediment to
this is that the laborer cannot enforce repayment from the farmer (because the output is
not pledgeable and the laborer has no way to seize it). Therefore, the farmer’s promise
9
Figure 3: The warehouse’s balance sheet expands when it makes a loan, cre-
ating liquidity.
Balance sheet before lending Balance sheet after lending
grain receipts grain receipts
liquidity creation
loan fake receipts
to the laborer is not credible.
First-best. We now consider the first best allocation of resources in order to
emphasize that the incentive compatibility constraint limits liq uidity creation. Allowing
warehouses to make loans in fake receipts moves the economy closer to the first best
level of liquidity creation, but does not achieve it. In the first-best allocation the farmer
invests his entire endowment in capital i = e = 12 and laborers exert equal labor = 12.
In this allocation output y = 4i = 48 and liquidity creation is given by
Λ
fb
=
i + w
e
=
12 + 12
12
= 2. (6)
Figure 4: Summary of liquidity creation the example in Section 2.
Case
Date 1 Output y Date 2 Output Liquidity Λ
No warehouses 24 19.2 1
Warehouses without lending 24 24 1
Warehouses with lending
40 40 5/3
First-best 48 48 2
3
Model
There are three dates, Date 0, Date 1, and Date 2 and three groups of players, farmers,
warehouses, and laborers. There is a unit continuum of each type of player. There
is one real good, called grain, which serves as the numeraire. There are also receipts
issued by warehouses, which entail the right to withdraw grain from a warehouse.
10
All players are risk neutral and consume only at Date 2. Denote farmers’ consump-
tion by c
f
, laborers’ consumption by c
l
, and the warehouses’ consumption by c
b
(the
index b stands for “bank”). Farmers begin life with an endowment e of grain. No other
player has a grain endowment. Laborers have labor at Date 0. They can provide labor
at the constant marginal cost of one. So their utility is c
l
. Farmers have access
to the following technology. At Date 0, a farmer invests i units of grain and units of
labor. At Date 1, this investment yields
y = A min {αi, } , (7)
i.e. the production function is Leontief. The output y is not pledgeable. At Date 1
farmers have no special production technology: they can either store grain privately or
store it in a warehouse.
If grain is not invested in the technology, it is either stored privately or stored in a
warehouse. If the grain is stored privately (by either farmers or laborers), it depreciates
at rate δ [0, 1). If player j stores s
j
t
units of grain privately from Date t to Date t + 1,
he has (1 δ)s
j
t
units of grain at Date t + 1. If grain is stored in a warehouse, it does
not depreciate. Further, if grain is stored in the warehouse, the warehouse can seize it.
The assumption that the warehouse can store grain more efficiently than the in-
dividual farmer has a natural interpretation in the context of the original warehouses
from which banks evolved. These ancient warehouses tended to be (protected) temples
or the treasures of sovereigns, so they had more power than ordinary individuals and a
natural advantage in safeguarding valuables and enforcing contracts.
9
Our assumption
on δ can thus be viewed either as a technological advantage arising from specializa-
tion acquired through (previous) investment and experience or as a consequence of the
power associated with the warehouse.
10
When players store grain in warehouses, warehouses issues receipts as “proof of
these deposits. The bearers of receipts can trade them among themselves. Warehouses
can also issue receipts that are not proof of deposits. These receipts, which we refer to
as “fake receipts,” still entail the right to withdraw grain from a warehouse, and thus
they are warehouses’ liabilities that are not backed by the grain they hold. Receipts
9
We thank Charles Goodhart for this interpretation. Thus, whereas our focus is on private money (fake
receipts), the alternative, sovereign-power-linked interpretation of the storage advantage of the warehouse
over individuals means tha t our model may complement the chartalist view of money creation by the state
(e.g. Knapp (1924) and Minsky (2008)).
10
This power was important for several reasons that complement our approach and provide alternative
interpretations of the deep parameters in the model. First, it enabled grain, gold, or other valuable com-
modities to be s tored safely, without fear of robbery. Second, power enabled the creditor to impose greater
penalties on defaulting borrowers. Third, power also generated a greater likelihood of continuation of the
warehouse, and hence of engaging in a r e peated game with depositors. This created reputational incentives
for the warehouse not to abscond with deposits.
11
backed by grain are indistinguishable from fake receipts.
The markets for labor, warehouse deposits, and loans are competitive.
3.1 Financial Contracts
There are three types of contracts in the economy: labor contracts, deposit contracts,
and lending contracts. We restrict attention to bilateral contracts, although warehouse
receipts are tradeable and loans are also tradeable in an interbank market.
Lab or contracts are between farmers and laborers. Farmers pay laborers w in
exchange for laborers’ investing in their technology, which then produces y = y(i, )
units of grain at Date 1.
Deposit contracts are between warehouses and the other players, i.e., laborers, farm-
ers, and (potentially) other warehouses. Warehouses accept grain deposits with gross
rate R
D
t
over one period, i.e. if player j {l, f } makes a deposit of d
j
t
units of grain
at Date t he has the right to withdraw R
D
t
d
j
t
units of grain at Date t + 1. When a
warehouse accepts a deposit of one unit of grain, it issues a receipt in exchange as
“proof of the deposit.
Lending contracts are between warehouses and farmers. Warehouses lend L to
farmers at Date 0 in exchange for farmers’ promise to repay R
L
L at Date 1, where R
L
is the lending rate. Warehouses can lend in grain or in receipts. A loan made in receipts
is tantamount to a warehouse offering a farmer a deposit at Date 0 in exchange for the
farmer’s promise to repay grain at Date 1. W hen a warehouse makes a loan in receipts,
we say that it is “issuing fake receipts.” We refer to a warehouse’s total deposits at
Date t as D
t
. These deposits include both those deposits backed by grain and those
granted as fake receipts.
Lending contracts are subject to a form of limited commitment on the farmers’ side.
Because farmers’ Date 1 output is not pledgeable, they are free to divert their output.
However, if the farmers do divert, they must store their grain privately. The reason is
that if they deposit their output in a warehouse, it may be seized by the warehouse.
We now formalize how we capture farmers’ inability to divert output if they deposit
in warehouses. We define the variable T as the total transfer from farmers to warehouses
at Date 1; T includes both the repayment of farmers’ debt to warehouses and farmers’
new deposits d
f
1
in warehouses. If farmers have borrowed B at Date 0, then they have
to repay R
L
B to warehouses at Date 1. W hen they make a transfer T to a warehouse at
Date 1, the “first” R
L
B units of grain they transfer to the warehouse are used to repay
the debt. Only after full repayment of R
L
B do warehouses store grain for farmers as
deposits. Thus, the farmers’ deposits at Date 1 are given by
d
f
1
= T min
T, R
L
B
= max
T R
L
B, 0
. (DC)
12
This says that if farmers have not repaid their debt at Date 1, their Date 1 deposits
are constrained to be zero; we call this the deposit constraint.
The argument above glosses over one important subtlety. The farmer could borrow
from one warehouse at Date 0 and divert his output at Date 1, on ly to deposit his grain
in a different warehouse. Would this allow the farmer to avoid both repaying his debt
and allowing his grain to depreciate? The answer is no. The reas on is as follows. If the
farmer deposits his grain in a warehouse that is not his original creditor, that warehouse
will buy the farmer’s debt from his original creditor on the interbank market, allowing
him to seize the grain the farmer owes. Thus, no matter which warehouse the farmer
deposits with, he will end up repaying his debt. We model the interbank market and
discuss this reasoning more formally in Appendix A.2.
Since there is no uncertainty, without loss of generality we can restrict attention to
lending contracts where default at Date 1 never happens in equilibrium. The farmer
will never default on his debt as long as repayment is incentive compatible. In other
words, he must prefer to repay his debt and deposit in the warehouse rather than to
default on his debt and store the grain privately. If g
f
1
denotes the farmer’s total Date
1 grain holding and R
L
B denotes the face value of his debt, then he repays his debt if
the following inequality is satisfied
11
R
D
1
g
f
1
R
L
B
(1 δ)g
f
1
. (IC)
The timeline of moves for each player and their contractual relationships are illus-
trated in a timeline in Figure 5.
11
In equilibrium, the fa rmer’s total Date 1 grain holding g
f
1
comprises his Date 1 output y, his Date 0
deposits gross of interest, R
D
0
d
f
0
, and his depreciated savings (1 δ)s
f
0
, or g
f
1
= y
i,
f
+ R
D
0
d
f
0
+ (1 δ)s
f
0
.
13
Figure 5: A Timeline Representation of Sequence of Moves
Date 0
Warehouses
accept deposits D
0
lend L to farmers
store s
b
0
Farmers
borrow B from warehouses
invest i and in technology y
pay laborers w
deposit d
f
0
in warehouses
store s
f
0
Laborers
exert labor
accept wage w
deposit d
l
0
in warehouses
store s
l
0
Date 1
Warehouses
receive T from farmers
accept deposits D
1
repay R
D
0
D
0
to depositors
store s
b
1
Farmers
receive cash flow y(i, )
transfer T to warehouses
receive R
D
0
d
f
0
from warehouses
have total grain holding g
f
1
deposit d
f
1
in warehouses
store s
f
1
Laborers
receive R
D
0
d
l
0
from warehouses
deposit d
l
1
in warehouses
store s
l
1
Date 2
Warehouses
repay R
D
1
D
1
to depositors
consume c
b
= s
b
1
R
D
1
D
1
Farmers
receive R
D
1
d
f
1
from warehouses
consume c
f
= R
D
1
d
f
1
+ (1 δ)s
f
1
Laborers
receive R
D
1
d
l
1
from warehouses
consume c
l
= R
D
1
d
l
1
+ (1 δ)s
l
1
3.2 Summary of Key Assumptions
In this subsection, we restate and briefly discuss the major assumptions underlying the
results.
Assumption 1. Output is not pledgeable.
This assumption prevents farmers’ from paying laborers directly in equity or debt. I f
farmers’ output were pledgeable, they could pay lab orers after their projects paid off.
Without this assumption, there would be no frictions and we could achieve the first-best
allocation. Thus, this assumption creates a role for banks as providers of liquidity.
Assumption 2. Warehouses can seize the deposits they hold.
This as sumption implies that a warehouse can enforce repayment from a farmer as long
as that farmer chooses to deposit in it. Whenever farmers deposit in a warehouse, the
warehouse has a seizure technology that allows it to demand repayment from farmers.
This is one key ingredient to understand the connection between warehousing/account-
keeping and lending. As discussed above and in Appendix A.2, the interbank market
14
for loans prevents farmers from avoiding repayment by depositing in warehouses that
are not their creditors.
Assumption 3. Grain depreciates relatively more slowly if stored in a warehouse.
Specifically, we us e the normalization that grain does not depreciate inside a warehouse
and depreciates at rate δ (0, 1] outside a warehouse. This assumption gives farmers
a reason to deposit in warehouses rather than store grain themselves—farmers deposit
in warehouses to take advantage of more efficient storage. This, in turn, ensures that
farmers will repay their debt, since warehouses can seize grain owed to them if it
is deposited with them, by Assumption 2. Thus, Ass umption 2 and As sumption 3
together imply that warehouses have a superior technology to enforce repay ment.
In some other theories of banking, the agents with the power to enforce contracts (or
“monitor borrowers”) naturally perform banking activities (e.g., Holmstrom and Tirole
(1997)). In our model, warehouse-banks’ enforcement power is an endogenous conse-
quence of their warehousing technology. Note that warehousing efficiency and enforce-
ment power are natural complements, as a superior warehousing technology may result
from the power to store assets safely, without f ear of robbery, as ex plained earlier.
Further, Assumption 2 implies that if a borrowers defaults, his access to warehousing
is limited in the future; this is analogous to warehouses’ having the power to impose
penalties on defaulting borrowers in a dynamic setting.
3.3 Individual Maximization Problems
All players take prices as given and maximize their Date 2 consumption subject to their
budget constraints. Farmers’ maximization problems are also subject to their incentive
compatibility constraint (IC).
We now write down each player’s maximization problem.
The warehouses’ maximization problem is
maximize c
b
= s
b
1
R
D
1
D
1
(8)
over s
b
1
, s
b
0
, D
0
, D
1
, and L subject to
s
b
1
= R
L
L + s
b
0
R
D
0
D
0
+ D
1
, (BC
b
1
)
s
b
0
+ L = D
0
, (BC
b
0
)
and the non-negativity constraints D
t
0, s
b
t
0, L 0. To understand this maxi-
mization program, note that equation (8) says that the warehouse maximizes its profit
(consumption) c
b
, which consists of the difference between what is stored in th e ware-
house at Date 1, s
b
1
, and what is paid to depositors, R
1
D
1
. Equation (BC
b
1
) is the
15
warehouse’s budget constraint at Date 1, which says that what is stored in the ware-
house at Date 1, s
b
1
, is given by the sum of the interest on the loan to the farmer, R
L
L,
the warehouse’s savings at Date 0, the deposits at Date 1 D
1
minus the interest the
warehouse must pay on its time 0 deposits, R
D
0
D
0
. Similarly, Equation (BC
b
0
) is the
warehouse’s budget constraint at Date 0, which says that the sum of the warehouse’s
savings at Date 0, s
b
0
, and its loans L must equal the sum of the Date 0 deposits, D
0
.
The farmers’ maximization problem is
maximize c
f
= R
D
1
d
f
1
+ (1 δ)s
f
1
(9)
over s
f
1
, s
f
0
, d
f
0
, T, i,
f
, and B subject to
d
f
1
= max
T R
L
B, 0
, (DC)
R
D
1
1 + δ
y
i,
f
+ R
D
0
d
f
0
+ (1 δ)s
f
0
R
D
1
R
L
B, (IC)
T + s
f
1
= y
i,
f
+ R
D
0
d
f
0
+ (1 δ)s
f
0
, (BC
f
1
)
d
f
0
+ s
f
0
+ i + w
f
= e + B, (BC
f
0
)
and the non-negativity constraints s
f
t
0, d
f
t
0, B 0, i 0,
f
0, T 0. The
farmer’s maximization program can be understood as follows. In equation (9) the farmer
maximizes his Date 2 consumption c
f
, which consists of his Date 1 dep os its gross of
interest, R
D
1
d
f
1
, and his depreciated private savings, (1 δ)s
f
1
. Equations (DC) and
(IC) are, respectively, the deposit constraint and the incentive compatibility constraint
(for an explanation see Subsection 3.1). The incentive compatibility constraint follows
directly from equation (IC) in Subsection 3.1, since the far mer’s Date 1 grain holding
g
f
1
comprises his Date 1 output y, his Date 0 deposits gross of interest, R
D
0
d
f
0
, and his
depreciated savings (1 δ)s
f
0
, or g
f
1
= y
i,
f
+ R
D
0
d
f
0
+ (1 δ)s
f
0
. Equation (BC
f
1
)
is the farmer’s budget constraint that says that the sum of his Date 1 savings, s
f
1
, and
his overall transfer to the warehouse, T , must equal the sum of his output y, his Date
0 deposits gross of interest, R
D
0
d
f
0
, and his depreciated savings, (1 δ)s
f
0
. Equation
(BC
f
0
) is the farmer’s budget constraint at Date 0 which says that the sum of his Date
0 deposits, d
f
0
, his Date 0 savings, s
f
0
, his investment in grain i and his investment in
labor, w
f
, must equal the sum of his initial endowment, e, and the amount he borrows,
B.
The laborers’ maximization problem is
maximize c
l
= R
D
1
d
l
1
+ (1 δ)s
l
1
l
(10)
16
over s
l
1
, s
l
0
, d
l
1
, d
l
0
, and
l
subject to
d
l
1
+ s
l
1
= R
D
0
d
l
0
+ (1 δ)s
l
0
, (BC
l
1
)
d
l
0
+ s
l
0
= w
l
, (BC
l
0
)
and the non-negativity constraints s
l
t
0, d
l
t
0,
l
0. The laborer’s maximization
program can be understood as follows. In equation (10) the laborer maximizes his
Date 2 consumption c
l
, which consists of his Date 1 deposits gross of interest, R
D
1
d
l
1
,
and his depreciated private savings, (1 δ)s
l
1
. Equation (BC
l
1
) is the laborer’s budget
constraint that says that the sum of his Date 1 savings, s
l
1
, and his Date 1 deposits, d
l
1
,
must equal the sum of his Date 0 deposits gross of interest, R
D
0
d
l
0
, and his depreciated
savings, (1 δ)s
l
0
. Equation (BC
l
0
) is the laborer’s budget constraint at Date 0 which
says that the sum of his Date 0 deposits, d
l
0
, and his Date 0 s avings, s
l
0
, must equal his
labor income w
l
.
3.4 Equilibrium
The equilibrium is a profile of prices hR
D
t
, R
L
, wi for t {1, 2} and a profile of alloca-
tions hs
j
t
, d
f
t
, d
l
t
, D
t
, L, B,
l
,
f
i for t {1, 2} and j {b, f, l} that solves the warehouses’
problem, the farmers’ problem, and the laborers’ problem defined in Section 3.3 and
satisfies the market clearing conditions for the labor market, the lending market, the
grain market and deposit market at each date:
f
=
l
(MC
)
B = L (MC
L
)
i + s
f
0
+ s
l
0
+ s
b
0
= e (MC
g
0
)
s
f
1
+ s
l
1
+ s
b
1
= (1 δ)s
f
0
+ (1 δ)s
l
0
+ s
b
0
+ y (MC
g
1
)
D
0
= d
f
0
+ d
l
0
(MC
D
0
)
D
1
= d
f
1
+ d
l
1
. (MC
D
1
)
3.5 Parameter Restrictions
In this section we make two restrictions on parameters. The first ensures that farmers’
production technology generates sufficiently high output that the investment is positive
NPV in equilibrium and the second ensures that the incentive problem that results
from the non-pledgeablity of farmers’ output is sufficiently severe to generate a binding
borrowing constraint in equilibrium. Note that since the model is linear, if the farmers’
IC does not bind, they will scale their production infinitely.
17
Parameter Restriction 1. The farmers’ technology is sufficiently productive,
A > 1 +
1
α
. (11)
Parameter Restriction 2. Depreciation from private storage is not too fast,
δA < 1. (12)
4
Model Solution
In this subsection, we solve the model to characterize the equilibrium. We proceed
as follows. First, we pin down the equilibrium deposit rates, lending rates and wages.
Then we show that the model collapses to the farmer’s problem which we then s olve to
characterize the equilibrium.
4.1 Preliminary Results
Here we state three results that completely characterize all the prices in the model,
namely the two depos it rates R
D
0
and R
D
1
, the lending rate R
L
, and the wage w. We
then show that given the eq uilibrium prices, farmers and laborers will never store grain
privately. The results all follow from the definition of competitive equilibrium with
risk-neutral agents.
The first two results say that the risk-free rate in the economy is one. This is natural,
since the warehouses have a scalable storage technology with return one.
Lemma 1. Deposit rates are one at each date, R
D
0
= R
D
1
= 1.
Now we turn to the lending rate. Since the farmers’ incentive compatibility con-
straint ensures that loans are riskless and warehouses are competitive, warehouses also
lend to f armers at rate one.
Lemma 2. Lending rates are one, R
L
= 1.
Finally, since laborers have a constant marginal cost of labor, the equilibrium wage
must be equal to this cost; this says that w = 1, as summarized in Lemma 3 below.
12
Lemma 3. Wages are one, w = 1.
12
Note that we have omitted the effect of discounting in the pr e ceding argument—laborers work at Date
0 and consume at Date 2; discounting is safely forgotten, though, since the laborers have access to a riskless
storage technology with r e tur n one via the warehouses, as esta blished above.
18
These results establish that the risk-free rate offered by warehouses exceeds the rate
of return from private storage, or R
D
0
= R
D
1
= 1 > 1δ. Thus, farmers and laborers do
not wish to make use of their private storage technologies. The only time a player may
choose to store grain outside a warehouse is if a farmer diverts his output; however,
the farmer’s incentive compatibility constraint ensures he will not do this. Corollary 1
below summarizes this reasoning.
Corollary 1. Farmers and laborers do not store grai n, s
l
0
= s
f
0
= s
l
1
= s
f
1
= 0.
4.2 Equilibrium Characterization
In this section we characterize the equilibrium of the model. We proceed as follows.
First, we show that given the equilibrium prices established in Subsection 4.1 above,
laborers and warehouses are indifferent among all allocations. We then establish that a
solution to the farmers’ maximization problem given the equilibrium prices is a solution
to the model.
The prices R
D
0
, R
D
1
, R
L
, and w are determined exactly so that the markets clear
given that agents are risk-neutral. In other words, they are the unique prices that
prevent the demands of warehouses or laborers from being infinite. This is the case
only if warehouses are indifferent between demanding and supplying deposits and loans
at rates R
D
0
, R
D
1
, and R
L
and laborers are indifferent between supplying or not supplying
labor at wage w. This implies that all prices are one in equilibrium, as summarized in
Lemma 4 below.
Lemma 4. Given the equilibrium prices, R
D
0
= R
D
1
= R
L
= w = 1, warehouse are
indifferent among all deposit and loan amounts and laborers are indifferent among all
labor amounts.
Lemma 4 implies that, given the equilibrium prices, they will absorb any excess
demand left by the farmers. In other words, given the equilibrium prices established in
Subsection 4.1 above, for any solution to the farmer’s individual maximization problem,
laborers’ and warehouses’ demands are such that markets clear.
We have thus established that the equilibrium allocation is given by the solution
to the farmers’ problem given the eq uilibrium prices, where the laborers’ and ware-
houses’ demands are determined by the market clearing conditions. Thus, to find the
equilibrium, we maximize the farmers’ Date 2 consumption subject to his budget and
incentive constraints given the equilibrium prices.
Lemma 5. The equilibrium allocation solves the problem to
maximize d
f
1
(13)
19
subject to
δ
y
i,
f
+ d
f
0
B, (IC)
d
f
1
+ B = y
i,
f
+ d
f
0
, (BC
f
1
)
d
f
0
+ i +
f
= e + B, (BC
f
0
)
and i 0,
f
0, B 0, d
f
0
0, and d
f
1
0.
Proposition 1. The equilibrium allocation is as follows:
B =
δAαe
1 + α
1 δA
, (14)
=
αe
1 + α
1 δA
, (15)
i =
e
1 + α
1 δA
. (16)
5
Benchmarks
In this s ection we consider two benchmarks, one in which warehouses cannot issue
fake receipts but mus t back all deposits with grain and another in which contracts are
perfectly enforceable, i.e. the first best.
5.1 Benchmark: No Fake Receipts
Consider a benchmark model in which warehouses cannot issue any receipts that are
not backed by grain. Since farmers have the entire endowment at Date 0, the ware-
house cannot lend. Thus, farmers simply divide their endowment between their capital
investment i and their labor investment ; their budget constraint reads
i + w = e. (17)
The Leontief production function implies that they will always make capital investments
equal to the fraction α of their labor investments, or
αi = ℓ. (18)
We summarize the solution to this benchmark model in Proposition 2 below.
Proposition 2. In the benchmark model in which warehouses cannot issue fake re-
20
ceipts, the equilibrium is as follows:
nr
=
αe
1 + α
, (19)
i
nr
=
e
1 + α
. (20)
Note that allocation in the benchmark without fake receipts coincides with what the
allocation would be if there were no warehouses, since warehouses are not storing any
grain at Date 0. Warehouses nonetheless lead to efficiency gains, because they provide
efficient storage of grain from Date 1 to Date 2; however, they have no effect at Date 0.
5.2 Benchmark: First-best
We now consider the first-best allocation. Here we consider the allocation that would
maximize total output subj ect only to market clearing conditions. Since the utility,
cost, and production functions are all linear, in the first-best allo cation, all resources
are allocated to the most productive players at each date. At Date 0 the farmers are
the most productive and at Date 1 the warehouses are the most productive. Thus, all
grain is held by farmers at Date 0 and by warehouses at Date 1. Laborers ex ert labor
in proportion 1 of the total grain invested to maximize production.
Proposition 3. In the fi rs t-best benchmark, the allocation is as follows:
fb
= αe, (21)
i
fb
= e. (22)
In Appendix A.3 we discuss the connection between our model and the classical
relending model in fractional reserve banking. In this model, warehouses make loans,
some fraction of these loans are redeposited by laborers and then loaned again by the
warehouse, some of these loans are then redeposited by laborers, and s o on. W ith no
constraints, this effective reuse of deposits yields the first-best allocation above.
6
Analysis of the Second-best
In this section we present the analysis of the second-best equilibrium. We show two
main results. First, warehouses create liquidity only when they make loans by issuing
fake receipts and, second, warehouses still hold grain in eq uilibrium, i.e. the incentive
constraint leads to “endogenous fractional reserves that prevent the economy from
reaching the first-best benchmark.
21
6.1 Liquidity Creation
In this section we turn to the liquidity a warehouse creates by lending in fake receipts.
We begin with the definition of a liquidity multiplier, which describes the total invest-
ment (grain investment plus labor investment) that farmers can undertake at Date 0
relative to the total endowment e.
Definition 1. The liquidity multiplier Λ
is the ratio of the equilibrium investment in
production i + w to the total grain endowment in the economy e,
Λ :=
i + w
e
. (23)
Note that we will refer to the total liquidity created by warehouses as the total invest-
ment i + w les s the initial liquidity e, which is given by i + w e = 1)e.
The next result compares the liquidity created in equilibrium, given that warehouses
can issue fake receipts, with the liquidity created in the benchmark in which warehouses
must back all receipts by grain.
Proposition 4. Banks create liquidity only w hen they can issue fake receipts. In
equilibrium, the liquidity multiplier is
Λ =
1 + α
1 + α
1 δA
> 1, (24)
whereas, in the benchmark model with no receipts, the liquidity multiplier is one, denoted
Λ
nr
= 1.
This result implies that it is the warehouse’s ability to make loans in fake receipts, not
its ability to take deposits, that creates liquidity in the econ omy. Warehouses lubricate
the economy because they lend in fake receipts rather than in grain. They can do this
because of their dual function: they keep accounts (i.e. warehouse grain) and also make
loans. This is the crux of farmers’ incentive constraint: because warehouses provide
valuable warehousing services, farmers go to these warehouse-banks and deposit their
grain, which is then also the reason why they repay their debts.
To cement the argument that liquidity creation results only from warehouses’ lending
in fake receipts, we now relate the quantity of fake receipts that the warehouse issues
to the liquidity multiplier. The number of fake receipts the warehouse issues at Date 0
is given by the total number of receipts it issues D
0
less the total quantity of grain it
stores s
b
0
; in equilibrium, this is given by
D
0
s
b
0
=
αδAe
1 + α
1 δA
. (25)
22
The expression in Proposition 4 reveals that the number of fake receipts is proportional
to the amount of liquidity created in the economy. This reiterates our main point:
warehouses create liquidity only by lending in fake receipts. We s ummarize this in
Corollary 2 below.
Corollary 2. The total liquidity created at Date 0 equals the number of fake receipts
the warehouse issues
1) e = D
0
s
b
0
. (26)
We now analyze the effect of the private storage technology—i.e. the depreciation
rate δ—on warehouses’ liquidity creation. We find that the amount of liquidity Λ that
warehouses create is increasing in warehouses’ storage advantage, as measured by δ.
The reason is that the more desirable it is for farmers to deposit in a warehouse at
Date 1 rather than store privately, the looser is their incentive constraint. As a result,
warehouses are more wiling to lend to them at Date 0—they know they can lend more
and it will s till be incentive compatible for farmers to repay at Date 1. We can see this
immediately by differentiating the liquidity multiplier with respect to δ:
Λ
δ
=
(1 α)A
1 + α(1 δA)
2
> 0. (27)
We summarize this result in Corollary 3 below.
Corollary 3. The more efficiently warehouses can store grain relative to farmers (the
higher is δ), the more liquidity warehouses create by issuing fake receipts.
We note that Corollary 3 may seem counterintuitive: a decrease in the efficiency in
private storage leads to an increase in overall efficiency. The reason is that it allows
banks to create more liquidity by weakening farmer’s incentive to divert capital. We
return to this result when we discuss central bank policy in Subsection 7.3 below.
This result also suggests an empirical implication. To the extent that warehouses
have “power” in enforcing contracts, we should expect warehousing services to be more
important in countries with weaker prop erty rights.
6.2 Fractional Reserves
We now proceed to analyze warehouse balance sheets. Absent reserve requirements,
do they still store grain? We find that the answer is yes, even though the farmers’
technology is constant-returns-to-scale, and farmers would therefore prefer to invest all
grain in the economy in their technology. The reason that warehouses store grain in
equilibrium is that the farmers’ incentive constraint puts an endogenous limit on the
23
amount that farmers can borrow in dollars and, therefore, on the amount of grain that
they can invest productively.
Proposition 5. Warehouses hold a positive fraction of grain at t = 0, in equilibrium,
s
b
0
= e i =
α
1 δA
e
1 + α
1 δA
> 0, (28)
i.e. the incentive constraint leads to endogenous fractional reserves.
Note that in our model, the storage of grain by warehouses at Date 0 is inefficient.
Grain could be put to better use by farmers (in conjunction with labor paid for in
fake receipts). Thus, a policy maker in our model actually wishes to reduce warehouse
holdings or bank capital reserves, to have the economy operate more efficiently.
7
Welfare and Policy
In this section we consider the implications of four policies, all of which have been
advocated by policy-makers after the financial crisis of 2007–2009. These are: (1)
narrow banking, (ii) liquidity requirements for banks, (iii) capital requirements for
banks, and (iv) tightening monetary policy.
7.1 Liquidity Requirements and Narrow Banks
Basel III, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision’s third accord, extends inter-
national financial regulation to include so-called liquidity requirements. Specifically,
Basel III mandates that banks must hold a sufficient quantity of liquidity to ensure
a “liquidity ratio” called the Liquidity Coverage Ratio (LCR) is satisfied. The ratio
effectively forces banks to invest a portion of their assets in cash and cash-proximate
marketable securities. The rationale is that banks should be able to liquidate a portion
of their balance sheets expeditiously to withstand withdrawals in a crisis.
In our model, the LCR imposes a limit on the ratio of loans that a bank (warehouse)
can make relative to deposits (grain) it stores. This is exactly a limit on the quantity
of fake receipts a bank can issue or a limit on liquidity creation.
We now make this more formal. Consider a liquidity regulation that, like the LCR,
mandates that a bank hold a proportion θ of its assets in liquid assets, or
liquid assets
total assets
θ. (29)
In our model, the warehouses’ liquid assets are the grain they store and their total
assets are the grain they store plus the loans they make. Thus, within the model, the
24
liquidity regulation described above prescribes that, at Date 0,
s
b
0
B + s
b
0
θ. (30)
We see immediately by rewriting this inequality that this regulation imposes a cap on
bank lending,
B
1 θ
θ
s
b
0
. (31)
The next proposition states the circumstance in which liquidity regulation constrains
liquidity creation to a level below the equilibrium level.
Proposition 6. Whenever the required liquidity ratio θ is such that
θ > 1 δA, (32)
liquidity regulation inhibits liquidity creation—and thus farmers’ investment—below the
equilibrium level.
Advocates of so-called narrow banking have argued that banks should hold only
liquid securities as assets, with some arguing for banks to invest only in treasuries,
effectively requiring one-hundred percent reserves.
13
In our model, this corresponds to
θ = 1 in the analysis of the LCR, which reduces to the benchmark in which warehouses
cannot make loans. We state this as a proposition for emphasis.
Proposition 7. The requirement of narrow banking is equivalent to the benchmark in
which warehouse cannot issue fake receipts (Section 5). In this case there is no liquidity
creation, Λ
nr
= 1.
7.2 Bank Capital and Liquidity Creation
In this subsection we analyze the implications of changes in bank capital for warehouse
liquidity creation.
14
In particular, we show that increasing warehouse equity increases
liquidity creation. To do this we extend the model in the following way. Between
Date 1 and Date 2 we introduce the possibility that grain may spoil even if stored
in a warehouse and that the warehouse may reduce the probability of spoilage by
exerting (unobservable) costly effort at the end of Date 1. Specifically, with probability
1 warehoused grain does not depreciate, and with probability warehoused grain
depreciates entirely. Warehouses exert effort to decrease the probability , where the
13
See the review by Pennacchi (2012).
14
Because we do not have bank failures and crises in our model, our analysis understates the value and
role of bank capital. Calomiris and Nissim (2014) document that the market is attaching a higher value to
bank capital after the 2007–09 crisis.
25
cost of effort is γ(1 ∆)
2
/2. We also assume that the warehouse has an exogenous
endowment E of grain at Date 1. We impos e a parameter restrictions that equity is
neither too small nor too large, so we obtain an interior solution.
Parameter Restriction 3.
γ(1 δ) < E γ. (33)
If the grain in the warehouse spoils, the warehouse has no grain to repay its depos-
itors and it defaults. Finally, note that we leave the model unchanged at Date 0 for
simplicity.
We proceed to show that increasing bank capital, i.e. increasing warehouses’ Date 1
equity E, increases the liquidity multiplier Λ, thereby elevating liquidity creation. This
result contrasts with Proposition 6 above, demonstrating that liquidity requirements
and capital requirements are by no means substitutes; the two regulatory policies have
opposite effects on liquidity creation in our model.
We solve the model backwards, first finding the equilibrium level of effort that
warehouses exert to prevent spoilage. Note that the warehouses choose their effort to
maximize their Date 2 payoffs, given their grain holdings s
b
1
, their deposits D
1
, and the
deposit rate R
D
1
:
c
b
= (1 ∆)
s
b
1
R
D
1
D
1
γ
2
1 ∆)
2
. (34)
We solve for the maximum via the first-order condition. The equilibrium effort level is
stated in Lemma 6 below.
Lemma 6. In equilibrium, warehouses determine their effort such that
1 =
s
b
1
R
D
1
D
1
γ
. (35)
Next, we state a lemma describing the prices in the economy. The prices are all
one, as in the baseline model (Subsection 4.1). We state the result in Lemma 7 below,
but we first mention one subtlety here. At Date 1, competitive banks offer the deposit
rate that makes them indifferent between accepting more deposits and not accepting
more deposits. Note that in the event of spoilage, warehouses always default, so the
deposit rate is irrelevant. In the event of no spoilage, their return on deposits is one,
as above. Thus, competition leads them to set R
D
1
= 1. Depositors prefer to deposit
in the warehouse as long as their expected payoffs from depositing exceed their payoffs
from storing privately. Taken together, Parameter Restriction 3 and Lemma 6 above
ensure that this is always the case and farmers and laborers still prefer to deposit in a
warehouse than to store privately in equilibrium.
26
Lemma 7. R
D
0
= R
D
1
= R
L
= w = 1.
We can now analyze the effect of warehouse capital on the farmers’ incentive con-
straint. Farmers will deposit in a warehouse as long as the benefits provided by ware-
houses’ superior storage technology outweigh the costs of repaying their debt, or, given
R
D
1
= R
L
= 1,
(1 δ)y (1 ∆)(y B). (36)
Observe that the right-hand side of the incentive constraint above takes into account
that farmers receive nothing with probability because their grain spoils. We can
substitute in for from Lemma 6 above and find that the amount farmers can borrow
is
B
s
b
1
R
D
1
D
1
γ(1 δ)
s
b
1
R
D
1
y. (37)
Solving for s
b
1
from the warehouses’ Date 1 budget constraint (remembering to take into
account their additional endowment E) and substituting in for the prices from Lemma
7 above, we see that
s
b
1
= E + R
L
L + D
0
L R
D
0
D
0
+ D
1
(38)
= E + D
1
. (39)
Hence, we find that the amount that farmers can borrow is bounded by a function of
warehouses equity, specifically
B
1
γ(1 δ)
E
y. (40)
The bound on the right-hand side above is a function of warehouse equity E. In
other words, the warehouse’s willingness to lend at Date 0 is increasing in its capital.
In equilibrium, this implies that the more capital the warehouse has, the more fake
receipts it prints and the more liquidity it creates at Date 0. This is summarized in
Proposition 8 below.
Proposition 8. Increasing warehouse equity increases liquidity creation,
Λ
E
> 0. (41)
This result stands in sharp contrast to the existing models literature on bank liq-
uidity creation. In models like Bryant (1980) and Diamond and Dybvig (1983), there
is no discernable role for bank capital, and models like Diamond and Rajan (2001) ar-
gue that higher bank capital will diminish liquidity creation by banks. In our model,
higher bank capital expands the bank’s lending capacity and hence enhances ex ante
27
liquidity creation. Nonetheless, we have no central bank and no frictions that generate
a rationale for regulatory capital requirements.
7.3 Monetary Policy
In this subsection we analyze the implications of changes in monetary policy on ware-
house liquidity creation. We define the central bank rate R
CB
as the (gross) rate at
which warehouses can deposit with the central bank.
15
This is analogous to the s torage
technology of the warehouse yielding return R
CB
. In this interpretation of the model,
grain is central bank money and fake receipts are private money.
We first state the necessary analogs of the parameter restrictions in Subsection 3.5.
Note that they coincide with Parameter Restriction 1 and Parameter Restriction 2 when
R
CB
= 1, as in the baseline model.
Parameter Restriction 1
. The farmers’ technology is sufficiently productive,
A >
1
R
CB
+
R
CB
α
. (42)
Parameter Restriction 2
. Depreciation from private s torage is not too fast,
A
R
CB
1 + δ
< 1. (43)
The preliminary results of Subsection 4.1 lead to the natural modifications of the
prices. In particular, due to competition in the deposit market, the deposit rates equal
the central bank rate. Further, because laborers earn interest on their deposits, they
accept lower wages. We now summarize these results in Lemma 8.
Lemma 8. When warehouses earn the central ban k rate R
CB
on deposits, in equilibrium,
the deposit rates, lending rate, and wage are as follows:
R
D
0
= R
D
1
= R
L
= R
CB
(44)
and
w =
R
CB
2
. (45)
The crucial takeaway from the result is that the warehouse pays a higher dep osit
rate when the central bank rate is higher. This means that the farmer’s incentive
constraint takes into account a higher return from depositing in a warehouse, but the
15
We are considering a rather limited aspect of central bank monetary policy here, thereby ignor-
ing things like the role of the central bank in setting the interest rate on interbank lending, as in
Freixas, Martin, and Skeie (2011), for example.
28
same depreciation rate from private storage. Formally, with the central bank rate R
CB
,
the farmers’ incentive constraint at Date 1 reads
(1 δ)y R
CB
y R
CB
B
(46)
or
B
1
R
CB
1
1 δ
R
CB
y. (47)
Observe that whenever farmers are not too highly levered—B < y
2R
CB
2
—increasing
R
CB
loosens the incentive constraint. The reason is that it makes warehouse s torage
relatively more attractive at Date 1, inducing farmers to repay their debt rather than
to divert capital. (The reason that increasing R
CB
does not loosen the constraint when
B is high, it that it also increases the lending rate between Date 0 and Date 1.)
Proposition 9. A tightening of monetary policy (an increase in R
CB
) increases liq-
uidity creati on Λ as long as α + 2R
CB
(1 δ) >
R
CB
2
(otherwise it decreases liquidity
creation).
This contrasts with the established idea that low interest rates (easy money policy)
stimulate bank lending and help the economy recover from a recession.
16
In our model,
high interest rates allow banks to lend more because they loosen the farmers’ incentive
compatibility constraint by giving warehouses a greater advantage in storage. This
result complements Corollary 3, that says that liquidity creation is increasing in the
depreciation rate δ. Both results say that the better warehouses are at storing grain
relative to farmers, the more warehouses can lend.
8
Conclusion
Summary of p aper. In this paper we have developed a new theory of banking that is
tied to the origins of banks as commodity warehouses. The raison d’être for banks does
not require asymmetric information, screening, monitoring or risk aversion. Rather,
we show that the institutions with the best storage (warehousing) technology have an
advantage in enforcing contracts, and are therefore not only natural deposit-takers but
are als o natural lenders—i.e. they are natural banks. With this theory we show how
banks create liquidity even when they do not provide superior risk sharing. While the
existing literature views bank liquidity creation as being synonymous with improved risk
sharing for risk-averse depositors, we focus on ex ante funding liquidity creation, which
is the bank-attributed increase in the initially available liquidity that can be channeled
16
See, for example, Keeton (1993). Mishkin (2010) provides a broad assessment of monetary policy, bank
lending, and the role of the central bank.
29
into aggregate investment in productive activities. The key to the bank’s ability to do
this is the issuance of “fake” warehouse receipts by the bank. This creates a striking
contrast with the existing literature, which views the process of liquidity creation as
banks accepting deposits that are then loaned out, i.e., deposits create loans. In our
theory, loans also create deposits. We thus decouple the notion of creating liquidity
from risk preferences and show that risk aversion is neither a sufficient nor necessary
condition for ex ante liquidity creation. In this way, our analysis of bank liquidity
creation complements the focus of the existing literature on the bank creating liquidity
through better risk sharing.
Our theory has regulatory implications. It shows that proposals like narrow banking
and liquidity requirements on banks will diminish bank liquidity creation and be inim-
ical to economic growth. By contrast, higher levels of bank capital will enhance bank
liquidity creation. Moreover, we establish conditions under which a tighter monetary
policy induces more liquidity creation.
Empirical implications. Our paper generates numerous predictions that could be
tested. First, across countries, banks that provide warehousing services should play a
more important role in countries with weaker property rights. Second, more aggregate
funding liquidity will be created in the economy when banks have higher capital. Third,
liquidity requirements on banks will reduce aggregate liq uidity creation.
Future r esearch. We view this paper as a first step in the direction of formalizing
the funding liquidity creation role of banks in the context of safeguarding. Much remains
to be done. A few ex tensions come immediately to mind. One is to investigate the effects
of frictions in the interbank loan market. Another is to examine the implications of
alternative production technologies for farmers, e.g. Cobb–Douglas. Finally, we have
not considered the potential bank fragility associated with the creation of liquidity in
our model of warehouse banking, an issue that will create a natural role for a central
bank, and one that should be addressed in future research.
17
But our paper emphasizes
that the creation of funding liquidity is not one that inherently generates fragility—
other ingredients need to be added to the recipe for that to happen.
17
See Goodhart (2010) for a thor ough dis c ussion of the role of central banks and how it is changing.
30
A Appendix
A.1 Proofs
A.1.1 Proof of Lemma 1
We show the result by contradiction. If R
D
t
6= 1 in equilibrium, deposit markets cannot
clear.
First suppose (in anticipation of a contradiction) that R
D
t
< 1 in equilibrium (for
either t {0, 1}). Now set s
b
t
= D
t
in the warehouse’s problem in Subsection 3.3.
The warehouse’s objective function (equation (8)) goes to infinity as D
t
without
violating the constraints. The dep osit markets therefore cannot clear if R
t
< 1, a
contradiction. We conclude that R
D
t
1.
Now suppose (in anticipation of a contradiction) that R
D
t
> 1 in equilibrium (f or
either t {0, 1}). Now set s
b
t
= D
t
in the warehouses problem. The warehouse’s ob-
jective function goes to infinity as D
t
−∞ without violating the budget constraints.
Thus, if R
D
t
> 1, it must be that D
t
= 0. However, since the depreciation rate δ > 0,
the demand from laborers and farmers to s tore grain is strictly positive for R
D
t
> 1 δ.
Thus, again, deposit markets cannot clear, a contradiction. We conclude that R
D
t
1.
The two contradictions above taken together imply that R
D
t
= 1 for t {0, 1}.
A.1.2 Proof of Lemma 2
We show the result by contradiction. If R
L
6= 1 in equilibrium, loan markets cannot
clear.
First suppose (in anticipation of a contradiction) that R
L
> 1 in equilibrium. Now
set L = D
t
in the warehouse’s problem in Subsection 3.3. Given that R
D
0
= 1 from
Lemma 1 above, the warehouse’s objective function (equation 8) goes to infinity as
L without violating the constraints. The deposit markets therefore cannot clear
if R
L
> 0, a contradiction. We conclude that R
L
1.
Now suppose (in anticipation of a contradiction) that R
L
< 1 in equilibrium. Now
set L = D
0
in the warehouse’s problem. Given that R
D
0
= 1 from Lemma 1 above, the
warehouse’s objective function goes to infinity as L −∞ without violating the budget
constraints. Thus, if R
L
< 1, it must be that D
0
= 0. However, since the depreciation
rate δ > 0, the demand from laborers and farmers to store grain is always strictly
positive for R
D
t
> 1 δ. Thus, again, deposit markets cannot clear, a contradiction.
We conclude that R
L
1.
The two contradictions above taken together imply that R
L
= 1.
31
A.1.3 Proof of Corollary 1
Given Lemma 1 above, the result is immediate from inspection of the farmer’s problem
and the laborer’s problem in Subsection 3.3 given that R
D
0
= R
D
1
= 1 > 1 δ, the
return from private storage.
A.1.4 Proof of Lemma 3
We show the result by contradiction. If w 6= 1 in eq uilibrium, labor markets cannot
clear.
First suppose (in anticipation of a contradiction) that w > 1 in equilibrium. From
Corollary 1, d
l
0
= w
l
and d
l
1
= R
D
0
d
l
0
in the laborer’s problem in Subsection 3.3. The
constraints collapse, and the laborer’s objective function (equation (10)) is R
D
1
R
D
0
wℓ
l
l
= (w 1)
l
, having substituted R
D
0
= R
D
1
= 1 from Lemma 1 above. Since w > 1
by supposition, the objective function approaches infinity as
l
without violating
the constraints. The labor market therefore cannot clear if w > 1, a contradiction. We
conclude that w 1.
Now suppose (in anticipation of a contradiction) that w < 1 in equilibrium. As
above, the laborer’s objective function is (w 1)
l
. Since w < 1 by suppos ition, the
laborer sets
l
= 0. The farmer, however, always has a strictly positive demand for
labor if w < 1—he produces nothing without labor and his productivity A > 1 + 1
by Parameter Restriction 1. The labor market therefore cannot clear if w < 1, a
contradiction. We conclude that w 1.
The two contradictions above taken together imply that w = 1.
A.1.5 Proof of Lemma 4
The result follows immediately from the proofs of Lemma 1, Lemma 2, and Lemma 3,
which pin down the prices in the model by demonstrating that if prices do not make
these players indifferent, markets cannot clear, contradicting equilibrium.
A.1.6 Proof of Lemma 5
The result follows from Lemma 4 and s ubstituting in prices and demands from the
preliminary results in Subsection 4.1. In short, since, given the equilibrium prices,
laborers and warehouses are indifferent among allocations, they will take on the excess
demand left by the farmers to clear the market.
32
A.1.7 Proof of Proposition 1
We begin by rewriting the farmer’s problem in Lemma 5 as
maximize d
f
1
(48)
subject to
δ
A max
αi,
f
+ d
f
0
B, (IC)
d
f
1
+ B = A max
αi,
f
+ d
f
0
, (BC
f
1
)
d
f
0
+ i +
f
= e + B, (BC
f
0
)
and i 0,
f
0, B 0, d
f
0
0 and d
f
1
0.
Now observe that at the optimum, max
αi,
f
=
f
and
f
= αi. Further, elimi-
nate the d
f
1
of the objective from the budget constraint. Now we can write the problem
as
maximize Aℓ
f
+ d
f
0
B (49)
subject to
δ
Aℓ
f
+ d
f
0
B, (IC)
d
f
0
+ i +
f
= e + B, (BC
f
0
)
f
= αi (50)
and i 0,
f
0, B 0, and d
f
0
0.
We see that the budget constraint and
f
= αi imply that
B = d
f
0
+
1 + α
α
f
e (51)
and, thus, the objective is
Aℓ
f
1 + α
α
f
+ e =
α(A 1) 1
α
f
+ e. (52)
This is increasing in
f
by Parameter Restriction 1, so
f
is maximal at the optimum.
Thus, the incentive constraint binds, or
δ
Aℓ
f
+ d
f
0
= B = d
f
0
+
1 + α
α
f
e. (53)
or
e (1 δ)d
f
0
=
1 δA +
1
a
f
. (54)
33
Since, by Parameter Restriction 2, δA < 1, setting d
f
0
= 0 maximizes
f
. Hence,
f
=
αe
1 + α
1 δA
. (55)
Combining this with the budget constraint and the equation i =
f
gives the expres-
sions in the proposition.
A.1.8 Proof of Proposition 2
The equilibrium allocation again solves the farmer’s problem, but in this case the ware-
house cannot issue more receipts than has deposits so s
b
0
0. Further, since the
warehouse has no endowment, its budget constraint reads L + s
b
0
= D
0
. Thus, L = 0.
Market clearing implies B = 0. The farmer’s problem is thus to
maximize d
f
1
(56)
subject to
d
f
1
= A max
n
αi,
f
o
, (57)
i +
f
= e. (58)
The solution to the problem is
nr
=
αe
1 + α
, (59)
i
nr
=
e
1 + α
, (60)
as expressed in the proposition.
A.1.9 Proof of Proposition 3
As discussed in the text preceding the statement of the prop osition, in the first-best
all grain is invested in its first-best use at Date 0. This corresponds to i
fb
= e, since
the farmer’s technology is the most productive. The production function requires
fb
=
αi = αe units of labor to be productive, and any more is unproductive. In summary,
i
fb
= e and
fb
= αe, as s tated in the proposition.
A.1.10 Proof of Proposition 4
The result follows immediately from comparison of the equilibrium expression for i+w
given in Proposition 1 with the expression for i
nr
+ w
nr
given in Proposition 2. Note
that w = 1 in the benchmark with no receipts as well as in the full model. The proofs of
34
the results for the prices (in particular for the wage w) in Subsection 4.1 are unchanged
for the benchmark.
A.1.11 Proof of Corollary 2
The result follows from direct calculation given the equilibrium expressions for Λ, D
0
and s
b
0
.
A.1.12 Proof of Corollary 3
The result is immediate from differentiation, as expressed in equation (27).
A.1.13 Proof of Proposition 5
The expression given in the proposition is positive as long as 1 δA > 0. This holds
by Parameter Restriction 2. The result follows immediately.
A.1.14 Proof of Proposition 6
The liquidity ration inhibits liquidity creation whenever warehouses’ equilibrium Date 0
grain holdings s
b
0
are insufficient to satisfy their liquidity requirements. In other words,
given equation (31 ), if
B <
1 θ
θ
s
b
0
, (61)
then liquidity requirements inhibit liquidity creation. Given the equilibrium values of
s
b
0
and B, this can be rewritten as
δAαe
1 + α
1 δA
<
1 θ
θ
α
1 δA
e
1 + α
1 δA
. (62)
This holds only if
θ < 1 δA. (63)
Whenever this inequality is violated, liquidity requirements inhibit liquidity require-
ments. It is the negation of the above equality stated in the proposition.
A.1.15 Proof of Lemma 6
The result is immediate from maximizing the objective function in equation (35).
A.1.16 Proof of Lemma 7
The proof is identical to those of the lemmata in Subsection 4.1.
35
A.1.17 Proof of Proposition 8
In order to show that increasing warehouse equity E increases liquidity creation Λ,
we first characterize the eq uilibrium in the extended model of Subsection 7.2. This
amounts to solving an analogous version of the farmer’s problem stated in Lemma 5.
Specifically, the equilibrium allocation maximizes d
f
1
subject to the modified incentive
constraint in eq uation (40) and the budget constraints. This reduces to solving the
system of equations
B =
1
γ(1 δ)
E
y, (64)
f
= αi, (65)
e + B = i +
f
(66)
where y = Aℓ. The solution of the system gives
B =
(1 γ(1 δ)/E) Aαe
1 + α αA (1 γ(1 δ)/E)
(67)
f
=
αe
1 + α αA (1 γ(1 δ)/E)
, (68)
i =
e
1 + α αA (1 γ(1 δ)/E)
(69)
Note that this allocation coincides with the allocation in Proposition 1 when warehouses
exert sufficient effort to prevent spoilage, that is when = 1 or E = γ.
Given the above equilibrium allocation, the liquidity multiplier is given by
Λ =
i + w
e
=
1 + α
1 + α αA (1 γ(1 δ)/E)
, (70)
which is increasing in E, as desired.
A.1.18 Proof of Lemma 8
The proofs that R
D
0
= R
D
1
= R
L
= R
CB
are all identical to the proofs of the analogous
results in Subsection 4.1 with the warehouses’ return on storage (which is one in the
baseline model) replaced with the central bank rate R
CB
. The result is simply that
warehouses lend and borrow at their cost of storage, which is a result of warehouses
being competitive.
The result that w =
R
CB
2
is also nearly the same as the proof of the analogous
result (Lemma 3) in Subsection 4.1. The modification is that the laborer’s objective
function (equation (10)) reduces to c
l
=
R
CB
2
wℓ , since the laborer invests its
income in the warehouse for two periods at gross rate R
CB
. In order for the laborer not
36
to supply infinite (positive or negative) labor , it must be that w =
R
CB
2
.
A.1.19 Proof of Proposition 9
Solving for the equilibrium again reduces to solving the farmer’s problem with binding
incentive and budget constraints. With the prices given in Lemma 8 these equations
are
R
CB
y R
CB
= (1 δ)y (71)
and
i +
R
CB
2
f
= e + B (72)
where y = A max {αi, } and, in equilibrium, i = αℓ
f
. From the budget constraint we
find that
f
=
α
R
CB
2
(e + B)
α + (R
CB
)
2
(73)
and, combining the above with the incentive constraint,
B =
αA
R
CB
1 + δ
e
α + (R
CB
)
2
αA (R
CB
1 + δ)
. (74)
This gives the following equilibrium allocation:
=
α
R
CB
2
e
α + (R
CB
)
2
αA (R
CB
1 + δ)
, (75)
i =
R
CB
2
e
α + (R
CB
)
2
αA (R
CB
1 + δ)
. (76)
We use the allocation to write down the liquidity multiplier Λ as
Λ =
i + w
e
(77)
=
α +
R
CB
2
α + (R
CB
)
2
αA (R
CB
1 + δ)
. (78)
We now compute the derivative of Λ with respect to R
CB
to show when increasing R
CB
increases Λ:
Λ
R
CB
=
2R
CB
h
α +
R
CB
2
αA
R
CB
1 + δ
i
R
CB
2
+ α
2R
CB
αA
h
α + (R
CB
)
2
αA (R
CB
1 + δ)
i
=
α + 2(1 δ)R
CB
R
CB
2
h
α + (R
CB
)
2
αA (R
CB
1 + δ)
i
2
.
37
This is positive exactly when α + 2R
CB
(1 δ) >
R
CB
2
as stated in the proposition.
A.2 The Interbank Market and the Incentive Constraint
The observation that a warehouse’s superior storage technology also serves as a superior
enforcement technology is at the center of our theory of warehouse banking. The key
to our argument is that farmers want to deposit their grain in warehouses to prevent
depreciation and that a warehouse holding a deposit can seize it. In Subsection 3.1,
we argued that this mechanism is robust to the possibility that a farmer may switch
warehouses, i.e. borrow from one warehouse at Date 0 and deposit in a different ware-
house at Date 1. The reason is that an interbank debt market ensures that whatever
warehouse he deposits in, the warehouse will always buy his debt and seize his grain.
We explore this in more detail and show that for any reasonable interbank market price
and any positive cost of switching warehouses, a farmer will always strictly prefer to
deposit with the warehouse he borrowed from (if the switching cost is zero, he still
weakly prefers to deposit in the warehouse he borrowed from). We include this as a
separate argument outside the baseline model because the analysis is game theoretic,
while our solution concept in the baseline model is competitive equilibrium.
Consider a farmer with grain g and outstanding debt with face value F < g to a
warehouse, called Warehouse 1. Assume that deposit rates are one (this is a result of
comp etition in the full model, stated in Lemma 7). The farmer can deposit his grain in
Warehouse 1 or in a different warehouse, Warehouse 2. We assume that if the farmer
deposits in Warehouse 2 he bears a switching cost ε. After the farmer has deposited in
a warehouse, Warehouse 1 may sell the farmer’s debt to Warehouse 2 at an exogenous
price p. If a warehouse has both the farmer’s debt and his deposit, the warehouse may
seize an amount F of the farmer’s deposit; otherwise, the warehouse with the farmer’s
debt does not collect. Finally, the warehouse that has accepted the deposit repays the
farmer (net of any seized grain). We focus on ε > 0 and p (0, F ). Formally, the
timing is as f ollows.
1. The farmer deposits g in Warehouse 1 or Warehouse 2
2. Warehouse 1 sells the farmer’s debt to Warehouse 2 or does n ot
3. If Warehouse 1 or Warehouse 2 has both the debt and the deposit, it seizes an
amount F of the deposit
4. The warehouse holding the deposit repays the farmer’s deposit (net of seized grain)
Note that in the game there are only two choices: first the farmer chooses Warehouse 1
or Warehouse 2 and second Warehouse 1 chooses to sell or not to sell. We have ass umed
seizure and deposit repayment as automatic.
38
We now proceed to solve the game by backward induction. We first consider the
case in which the farmer deposits in Warehouse 1. In this case, Warehouse 1 gets p
if it sells the farmer’s debt and F if it does not sell the farmer’s debt. Since F > p,
Warehouse 1 does not sell the farmer’s debt. The farmer’s payoff from depositing in
Warehouse 1 is thus g F .
Now consider the case in which the farmer deposits in Warehouse 2, bearing the
switching cost ε. In this case, Warehouse 1 gets p if it sells the farmer’s debt and zero
if it does not sell the farmer’s debt. Since p > 0, Warehouse 1 sells the farmer’s debt
to Warehouse 2. Warehouse 2 now holds both the farmer’s deposit and his debt and
therefore seizes an amount F . The farmer’s payoff from depos iting in Warehouse 2 is
thus g F ε.
Now turn do the farmer’s choice of where to deposit. If he deposits in Warehouse 1
he receives g F and if he deposits in Warehouse 2 he receives g F ε. Since ε > 0,
the farmer prefers to deposit in Warehouse 1. We state this result in a proposition for
emphasis.
Proposition 10. For any positive switching cost and any positive interbank price less
than the face value of debt, the farmer deposits in the warehouse he borrowed from in
the subgame perfect equilibrium.
This result says that a farmer cannot circumvent a warehouse’s ability to enforce con-
tracts by depositing in a warehouse different from the one he borrowed from. N ote
that this result does not depend on the fair pricing of debt in the interbank market, it
holds for any price less than the face value of debt. Since the farmer anticipates that no
matter the interbank price of his debt, the warehouse he deposits with will ultimately
hold his debt and then seize his deposit, the farmer prefers to deposit in the warehouse
he borrowed from. A warehouse anticipate this when it makes loans, so the deposit
constraint is as described in equation (DC) in Subsection 3.1.
A.3 Connection with the Relending Model
Here we ex plain how the first-best outcome above has an interpretation in the relending
model. In the relending model, banks take deposits, they use these deposits to make
loans, which are later depos ited again, and then lent out again, and so on. That the
bank has a deposit before bef ore it makes loans is the “deposits-first” view of bank
balance sheets. It contrasts with the “loans-first” perspective that we have stressed
thus far. In this loans-first view, banks create deposits (viz. fake receipts) when they
make loans. We show below that relending model yields the same first-best outcome
as stated in Proposition 3, implying that there is not necessarily a conflict between the
deposits-first and loans-first perspectives.
39
In relending model, there is a money multiplier which describes how much money
the banking system creates from an initial deposit. In textbook treatments the money
multiplier is the reciprocal of the reserve requirement, but we demonstrate below that
in our model it depends on the production technology.
Here we consider a sequential view of the equilibrium, analogous to Walrasian tâ-
tonnement, in which each player acts optimally in sequence of rounds. In Round n,
farmers divide their grain e
n
between capital investment i
n
and labor investment w
n
.
Since the farmers’ production function is A min {αi, }, they set αi
n
=
n
in each round.
Further, since wages are one, i
n
+
n
= e
n
and w
n
=
n
. Thus,
i
n
=
e
n
1 + α
and
n
=
αe
n
1 + α
. (79)
Lab orers then receive wages w
n
= αe
n
/(1 + α) which they deposit directly in ware-
houses, d
l
n
= αe
n
/(1+ α). Finally, in the first-best, warehouses lend out all their grain,
L
n
= d
l
n
= αe
n
/(1 + α). Round n + 1 begins with farmers having the borrowed grain
e
n+1
= L
n
. One round of this process is represented pictorially in Figure 6.
Now, note from the computations above that
e
n+1
=
αe
n
1 + α
(80)
From here, we compute e
n
recursively in terms of e
0
as
e
n
=
α
1 + α
n
e
0
. (81)
We now compute the first-best allocations of capital and labor investment given the
relending model. To do so, we sum up the per-round inves tments i
n
and
n
over an
infinite number of rounds, given the initial endowment e
0
= e, to recover
i
fb
=
X
n=0
i
n
(82)
=
X
n=0
e
n
1 + α
(83)
=
X
n=0
1
1 + α
α
1 + α
n
e (84)
= e, (85)
having used equation (81) and the formula for the sum of a geometric series. Likewise,
40
Figure 6: A Representation of the Relending Interpretation of the First-best
Warehouses
Farmers
invest i
n
=
e
n
1 + α
pay labor w
n
=
αe
n
1 + α
Laborers
deposit d
l
n
=
αe
n
1 + α
lend L
n
= d
l
n
grain e
n+1
= L
n
we find that
fb
=
X
n=0
n
(86)
=
X
n=0
αe
n
1 + α
(87)
=
X
n=0
α
1 + α
α
1 + α
n
e (88)
= αe. (89)
The ex press ions for i
fb
and
fb
under the relending model coincide with those in Proposi-
tion 3. Further, they suggest a natural money multiplier, stemming from the production
function. Of each unit of grain in the economy, a proportion 1/(1 + α) is invested in
capital and cannot be reused. The remainder is invested in labor, or working capital,
41
and therefore deposited back in the warehouse for reuse. These deposits are lend out,
and a proportion 1/(1 + α) is again invested in capital and the remainder is invested
in labor, which is deposited and reused. Thus, for every unit of grain, the amount that
can be invested is
Λ
fb
=
X
n=0
α
1 + α
n
= 1 + α. (90)
The multiplier Λ
fb
corresponds to a money multiplier in classical banking models.
This is the liquidity multiplier of Section 6. Note that the more important working
capital (labor ) is to production relative to physical capital (grain i), i.e. the higher is
α, the higher is the multiplier. Private money expands the money supply only to create
working capital. It cannot, of course, create physical capital out of thin air.
42
A.4 Table of Notations
Indices
f farmer index
l laborer index
b warehouse (bank) index
t {0, 1, 2} time index
Prices
R
D
t
deposit rate at Date t
R
L
lending rate at Date 0
w wages at Date 0
Demand and Supply
i grain farmers invest at Date 0
f
labor farmers demand at Date 0
l
labor laborers supply at Date 0
s
j
t
grain stored by player j at Date t
d
f
t
grain deposited in warehouses by farmers at Date t
d
l
t
grain deposited in warehouses by laborers at Date t
B loans demanded by farmers at Date 0
L loans supplied by warehouses at Date 0
D
t
overall deposits in warehouse at Date t
Production a nd Consumption
y farmer s output at Date 1
c
j
consumption o f player j at Date 2
Parameters
δ depreciatio n rate with private storag e
A productivity
α ratio of labor to grain in farmers’ production
e farmers’ (Date 0) endowment
E warehouses’ (Date 1) endowment (extension in Subsection 7.2)
γ cost parameter (extension in Subsection 7 .2)
Other Variables
g
f
1
farmer’s grain holding at Date 1
Λ liquidity multiplier
θ liquidity ratio (extension in Subsection 7.1)
probability of spoilage (extension in Subsection 7.2)
R
CB
central bank rate (extension in Subsection 7.3)
43
References
Allen, F., E. Carletti, and D. M. Gale (2014, September). Money, Financial Stability
and Efficiency. Journal of Economic Theory 149(8553), 100–127.
Allen, F. and D. Gale (1998). Optimal financial crises. The Journal of Finance 53,
1245–1284.
Allen, F. and D. Gale (2004, July). Financial intermediaries and markets. Economet-
rica 72(4), 1023–1062.
Berger, A. N. and C. H. S. Bouwman (2009). Bank liquidity creation. The Review of
Financial Studies 22 (9), pp. 3779–3837.
Bolton, P. and D. S. Scharfstein (1990, March). A theory of predation based on agency
problems in financial contracting. American Economic Review 80 (1), 93–106.
Brunnermeier, M. K. and L. H. Pedersen (2009). Market liquidity and funding liquidity.
Review of Financial Studies 22, 2201–2238.
Bryant, J. (1980). A model of reserves, bank runs, and deposit insurance. Journal of
Banking & Finance 4 (4), 335–344.
Calomiris, C. and D. Nissim (2014). Shifts in the market valuation of banking activities.
Journal of Financial Intermediation 23, 400–435.
Coval, J. D. and A. V. Thakor (2005). Financial intermediation as a beliefs-bridge
between optimists and pessimists. Journal of Financial Economics 75, 535–570.
Diamond, D. W. (1984). Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring. The
Review of Economic Studies 51 (3), pp. 393–414.
Diamond, D. W. and P. H . Dybvig (1983). Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity.
Journal of Political Economy 91, 410–419.
Diamond, D. W. and R. G. Rajan (2001). Liquidity risk, liquidty creation, and financial
fragility: A theory of banking. Journal of Political Economy 109, 287–327.
Freixas, X ., A. Martin, and D. Skeie (2011). Bank liquidity, interbank markets, and
monetary policy. Review of Financial S t udies 24 (8), 2656–2692.
Goodhart, C. A. (2010). The changing role of central banks. Working paper No. 326,
BIS.
44
Greenbaum, S., A. V. Thakor, and A. W. Boot (2015). Contemporary F inancial Inter-
mediation. Elsevier, Third Edition.
Hahn, A. (1920). Volkswirtschaftliche T heorie des Bankkredits. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr.
Hart, O. and J. Moore (1998, February). Default and renegotiation: A dynamic model
of debt. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 113 (1), 1–41.
Holmstrom, B. and J. Tirole (1997, August). Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds,
and the Real Sector. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (3), 663–91.
Holmström, B. and J. Tirole (2011). Inside and Outside Liquidity. The MIT Press.
Jacklin, C. (1987). Demand deposits, trading restrictions, and risk s haring. In
E. Prescott and N. Wallace (Eds.), C ontractual Arrangements for Intertemporal
Trade, Chapter II, pp. 26–47. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
Kashyap, A. K., R. Rajan, and J. C. Stein (2002, 02). Banks as Liquidity Providers:
An Explanation for the Coexistence of Lending and Deposit-Taking. Journal of
Finance 57 (1), 33–73.
Keeton, W. R. (1993). The impact of monetary policy on bank lending: The role of
securities and large CDS. Econ omic Review, The Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City, 35–47.
Knapp, G. F. (1924). The State Theory of Money. Number knapp1924 in History of
Economic Thought Books. McMaster University Archive for the History of Economic
Thought.
Lawson, W. (1855). The History of Banking. London: Richard Bentley.
Macmillan Committee (1931). British Parliamentary Reports on Interantional Finance:
The Report of the Macmillan Committee. London: H.M. Stationery Office.
Minsky, H. (2008). Stabilizing an Unstable Economy. McGraw-Hill.
Mishkin, F. (2010). Monetary policy strategy: Lessons from the crisis. Working paper,
Columbia University.
Pennacchi, G. (2012). Narrow banking. Annual Review of Fi nancial Economics 4,
141–159.
Postlewaite, A. and X. Vives (1987, June). Bank Runs as an Equilibrium Phenomenon.
Journal of Political Economy 95(3), 485–91.
45
Ramakrishnan, R. T. S. and A. Thakor (1984). Information reliability and a theory of
financial intermediation. Review of Economic Studies 51 (3), 415–32.
Skrastins, J. (2015). Firm boundaries and financial contracts . Working paper.
Werner, R. A. (2014). Can banks individually create money out of nothing? theories
and empirical evidence. Review of Financial Analysis 36, 1–19.
Wicks ell, K. (1907). The influence of the rate of interest on prices. Econ om ic Journal 17,
213–220.
Williams, J. (1986). Fractional reserve banking in grain. Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking 16, 488–496.
46